• Search Menu
  • Browse content in A - General Economics and Teaching
  • Browse content in A1 - General Economics
  • A10 - General
  • A11 - Role of Economics; Role of Economists; Market for Economists
  • A12 - Relation of Economics to Other Disciplines
  • A13 - Relation of Economics to Social Values
  • A14 - Sociology of Economics
  • Browse content in A2 - Economic Education and Teaching of Economics
  • A20 - General
  • A29 - Other
  • A3 - Collective Works
  • Browse content in B - History of Economic Thought, Methodology, and Heterodox Approaches
  • Browse content in B0 - General
  • B00 - General
  • Browse content in B1 - History of Economic Thought through 1925
  • B10 - General
  • B11 - Preclassical (Ancient, Medieval, Mercantilist, Physiocratic)
  • B12 - Classical (includes Adam Smith)
  • B13 - Neoclassical through 1925 (Austrian, Marshallian, Walrasian, Stockholm School)
  • B14 - Socialist; Marxist
  • B15 - Historical; Institutional; Evolutionary
  • B16 - History of Economic Thought: Quantitative and Mathematical
  • B17 - International Trade and Finance
  • B19 - Other
  • Browse content in B2 - History of Economic Thought since 1925
  • B20 - General
  • B21 - Microeconomics
  • B22 - Macroeconomics
  • B23 - Econometrics; Quantitative and Mathematical Studies
  • B24 - Socialist; Marxist; Sraffian
  • B25 - Historical; Institutional; Evolutionary; Austrian
  • B26 - Financial Economics
  • B27 - International Trade and Finance
  • B29 - Other
  • Browse content in B3 - History of Economic Thought: Individuals
  • B30 - General
  • B31 - Individuals
  • Browse content in B4 - Economic Methodology
  • B40 - General
  • B41 - Economic Methodology
  • B49 - Other
  • Browse content in B5 - Current Heterodox Approaches
  • B50 - General
  • B51 - Socialist; Marxian; Sraffian
  • B52 - Institutional; Evolutionary
  • B53 - Austrian
  • B54 - Feminist Economics
  • B55 - Social Economics
  • B59 - Other
  • Browse content in C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods
  • Browse content in C0 - General
  • C00 - General
  • C02 - Mathematical Methods
  • Browse content in C1 - Econometric and Statistical Methods and Methodology: General
  • C10 - General
  • C12 - Hypothesis Testing: General
  • C13 - Estimation: General
  • C14 - Semiparametric and Nonparametric Methods: General
  • C18 - Methodological Issues: General
  • C19 - Other
  • Browse content in C2 - Single Equation Models; Single Variables
  • C20 - General
  • C21 - Cross-Sectional Models; Spatial Models; Treatment Effect Models; Quantile Regressions
  • C22 - Time-Series Models; Dynamic Quantile Regressions; Dynamic Treatment Effect Models; Diffusion Processes
  • C23 - Panel Data Models; Spatio-temporal Models
  • C25 - Discrete Regression and Qualitative Choice Models; Discrete Regressors; Proportions; Probabilities
  • Browse content in C3 - Multiple or Simultaneous Equation Models; Multiple Variables
  • C30 - General
  • C32 - Time-Series Models; Dynamic Quantile Regressions; Dynamic Treatment Effect Models; Diffusion Processes; State Space Models
  • C34 - Truncated and Censored Models; Switching Regression Models
  • C38 - Classification Methods; Cluster Analysis; Principal Components; Factor Models
  • Browse content in C4 - Econometric and Statistical Methods: Special Topics
  • C43 - Index Numbers and Aggregation
  • C44 - Operations Research; Statistical Decision Theory
  • Browse content in C5 - Econometric Modeling
  • C50 - General
  • Browse content in C6 - Mathematical Methods; Programming Models; Mathematical and Simulation Modeling
  • C60 - General
  • C61 - Optimization Techniques; Programming Models; Dynamic Analysis
  • C62 - Existence and Stability Conditions of Equilibrium
  • C63 - Computational Techniques; Simulation Modeling
  • C65 - Miscellaneous Mathematical Tools
  • C67 - Input-Output Models
  • Browse content in C8 - Data Collection and Data Estimation Methodology; Computer Programs
  • C82 - Methodology for Collecting, Estimating, and Organizing Macroeconomic Data; Data Access
  • C89 - Other
  • Browse content in C9 - Design of Experiments
  • C90 - General
  • C91 - Laboratory, Individual Behavior
  • C92 - Laboratory, Group Behavior
  • C93 - Field Experiments
  • Browse content in D - Microeconomics
  • Browse content in D0 - General
  • D01 - Microeconomic Behavior: Underlying Principles
  • D02 - Institutions: Design, Formation, Operations, and Impact
  • D03 - Behavioral Microeconomics: Underlying Principles
  • Browse content in D1 - Household Behavior and Family Economics
  • D10 - General
  • D11 - Consumer Economics: Theory
  • D12 - Consumer Economics: Empirical Analysis
  • D13 - Household Production and Intrahousehold Allocation
  • D14 - Household Saving; Personal Finance
  • Browse content in D2 - Production and Organizations
  • D20 - General
  • D21 - Firm Behavior: Theory
  • D22 - Firm Behavior: Empirical Analysis
  • D23 - Organizational Behavior; Transaction Costs; Property Rights
  • D24 - Production; Cost; Capital; Capital, Total Factor, and Multifactor Productivity; Capacity
  • D25 - Intertemporal Firm Choice: Investment, Capacity, and Financing
  • Browse content in D3 - Distribution
  • D30 - General
  • D31 - Personal Income, Wealth, and Their Distributions
  • D33 - Factor Income Distribution
  • D39 - Other
  • Browse content in D4 - Market Structure, Pricing, and Design
  • D40 - General
  • D41 - Perfect Competition
  • D42 - Monopoly
  • D43 - Oligopoly and Other Forms of Market Imperfection
  • D46 - Value Theory
  • Browse content in D5 - General Equilibrium and Disequilibrium
  • D50 - General
  • D51 - Exchange and Production Economies
  • D57 - Input-Output Tables and Analysis
  • D58 - Computable and Other Applied General Equilibrium Models
  • Browse content in D6 - Welfare Economics
  • D60 - General
  • D61 - Allocative Efficiency; Cost-Benefit Analysis
  • D62 - Externalities
  • D63 - Equity, Justice, Inequality, and Other Normative Criteria and Measurement
  • D64 - Altruism; Philanthropy
  • D69 - Other
  • Browse content in D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making
  • D71 - Social Choice; Clubs; Committees; Associations
  • D72 - Political Processes: Rent-seeking, Lobbying, Elections, Legislatures, and Voting Behavior
  • D73 - Bureaucracy; Administrative Processes in Public Organizations; Corruption
  • D74 - Conflict; Conflict Resolution; Alliances; Revolutions
  • Browse content in D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty
  • D80 - General
  • D81 - Criteria for Decision-Making under Risk and Uncertainty
  • D82 - Asymmetric and Private Information; Mechanism Design
  • D83 - Search; Learning; Information and Knowledge; Communication; Belief; Unawareness
  • D84 - Expectations; Speculations
  • D85 - Network Formation and Analysis: Theory
  • D86 - Economics of Contract: Theory
  • D87 - Neuroeconomics
  • Browse content in D9 - Micro-Based Behavioral Economics
  • D91 - Role and Effects of Psychological, Emotional, Social, and Cognitive Factors on Decision Making
  • Browse content in E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics
  • Browse content in E0 - General
  • E00 - General
  • E01 - Measurement and Data on National Income and Product Accounts and Wealth; Environmental Accounts
  • E02 - Institutions and the Macroeconomy
  • Browse content in E1 - General Aggregative Models
  • E10 - General
  • E11 - Marxian; Sraffian; Kaleckian
  • E12 - Keynes; Keynesian; Post-Keynesian
  • E13 - Neoclassical
  • E16 - Social Accounting Matrix
  • E17 - Forecasting and Simulation: Models and Applications
  • Browse content in E2 - Consumption, Saving, Production, Investment, Labor Markets, and Informal Economy
  • E20 - General
  • E21 - Consumption; Saving; Wealth
  • E22 - Investment; Capital; Intangible Capital; Capacity
  • E23 - Production
  • E24 - Employment; Unemployment; Wages; Intergenerational Income Distribution; Aggregate Human Capital; Aggregate Labor Productivity
  • E25 - Aggregate Factor Income Distribution
  • E26 - Informal Economy; Underground Economy
  • E27 - Forecasting and Simulation: Models and Applications
  • Browse content in E3 - Prices, Business Fluctuations, and Cycles
  • E30 - General
  • E31 - Price Level; Inflation; Deflation
  • E32 - Business Fluctuations; Cycles
  • E37 - Forecasting and Simulation: Models and Applications
  • Browse content in E4 - Money and Interest Rates
  • E40 - General
  • E41 - Demand for Money
  • E42 - Monetary Systems; Standards; Regimes; Government and the Monetary System; Payment Systems
  • E43 - Interest Rates: Determination, Term Structure, and Effects
  • E44 - Financial Markets and the Macroeconomy
  • E49 - Other
  • Browse content in E5 - Monetary Policy, Central Banking, and the Supply of Money and Credit
  • E50 - General
  • E51 - Money Supply; Credit; Money Multipliers
  • E52 - Monetary Policy
  • E58 - Central Banks and Their Policies
  • Browse content in E6 - Macroeconomic Policy, Macroeconomic Aspects of Public Finance, and General Outlook
  • E60 - General
  • E61 - Policy Objectives; Policy Designs and Consistency; Policy Coordination
  • E62 - Fiscal Policy
  • E63 - Comparative or Joint Analysis of Fiscal and Monetary Policy; Stabilization; Treasury Policy
  • E64 - Incomes Policy; Price Policy
  • E65 - Studies of Particular Policy Episodes
  • Browse content in F - International Economics
  • Browse content in F0 - General
  • F00 - General
  • F01 - Global Outlook
  • F02 - International Economic Order and Integration
  • Browse content in F1 - Trade
  • F10 - General
  • F11 - Neoclassical Models of Trade
  • F12 - Models of Trade with Imperfect Competition and Scale Economies; Fragmentation
  • F13 - Trade Policy; International Trade Organizations
  • F14 - Empirical Studies of Trade
  • F15 - Economic Integration
  • F16 - Trade and Labor Market Interactions
  • F17 - Trade Forecasting and Simulation
  • F18 - Trade and Environment
  • Browse content in F2 - International Factor Movements and International Business
  • F20 - General
  • F21 - International Investment; Long-Term Capital Movements
  • F22 - International Migration
  • F23 - Multinational Firms; International Business
  • Browse content in F3 - International Finance
  • F30 - General
  • F31 - Foreign Exchange
  • F32 - Current Account Adjustment; Short-Term Capital Movements
  • F33 - International Monetary Arrangements and Institutions
  • F34 - International Lending and Debt Problems
  • F35 - Foreign Aid
  • F36 - Financial Aspects of Economic Integration
  • F37 - International Finance Forecasting and Simulation: Models and Applications
  • F39 - Other
  • Browse content in F4 - Macroeconomic Aspects of International Trade and Finance
  • F40 - General
  • F41 - Open Economy Macroeconomics
  • F42 - International Policy Coordination and Transmission
  • F43 - Economic Growth of Open Economies
  • F44 - International Business Cycles
  • F45 - Macroeconomic Issues of Monetary Unions
  • F47 - Forecasting and Simulation: Models and Applications
  • Browse content in F5 - International Relations, National Security, and International Political Economy
  • F50 - General
  • F51 - International Conflicts; Negotiations; Sanctions
  • F53 - International Agreements and Observance; International Organizations
  • F54 - Colonialism; Imperialism; Postcolonialism
  • F55 - International Institutional Arrangements
  • F59 - Other
  • Browse content in F6 - Economic Impacts of Globalization
  • F60 - General
  • F61 - Microeconomic Impacts
  • F62 - Macroeconomic Impacts
  • F63 - Economic Development
  • F64 - Environment
  • F65 - Finance
  • Browse content in G - Financial Economics
  • Browse content in G0 - General
  • G00 - General
  • G01 - Financial Crises
  • Browse content in G1 - General Financial Markets
  • G10 - General
  • G11 - Portfolio Choice; Investment Decisions
  • G12 - Asset Pricing; Trading volume; Bond Interest Rates
  • G13 - Contingent Pricing; Futures Pricing
  • G14 - Information and Market Efficiency; Event Studies; Insider Trading
  • G15 - International Financial Markets
  • G18 - Government Policy and Regulation
  • G19 - Other
  • Browse content in G2 - Financial Institutions and Services
  • G20 - General
  • G21 - Banks; Depository Institutions; Micro Finance Institutions; Mortgages
  • G22 - Insurance; Insurance Companies; Actuarial Studies
  • G23 - Non-bank Financial Institutions; Financial Instruments; Institutional Investors
  • G24 - Investment Banking; Venture Capital; Brokerage; Ratings and Ratings Agencies
  • G28 - Government Policy and Regulation
  • Browse content in G3 - Corporate Finance and Governance
  • G30 - General
  • G32 - Financing Policy; Financial Risk and Risk Management; Capital and Ownership Structure; Value of Firms; Goodwill
  • G33 - Bankruptcy; Liquidation
  • G34 - Mergers; Acquisitions; Restructuring; Corporate Governance
  • G35 - Payout Policy
  • G38 - Government Policy and Regulation
  • Browse content in G5 - Household Finance
  • G51 - Household Saving, Borrowing, Debt, and Wealth
  • Browse content in H - Public Economics
  • Browse content in H1 - Structure and Scope of Government
  • H10 - General
  • H11 - Structure, Scope, and Performance of Government
  • H12 - Crisis Management
  • Browse content in H2 - Taxation, Subsidies, and Revenue
  • H20 - General
  • H22 - Incidence
  • H23 - Externalities; Redistributive Effects; Environmental Taxes and Subsidies
  • H26 - Tax Evasion and Avoidance
  • Browse content in H4 - Publicly Provided Goods
  • H40 - General
  • H41 - Public Goods
  • Browse content in H5 - National Government Expenditures and Related Policies
  • H50 - General
  • H53 - Government Expenditures and Welfare Programs
  • H55 - Social Security and Public Pensions
  • H56 - National Security and War
  • Browse content in H6 - National Budget, Deficit, and Debt
  • H60 - General
  • H62 - Deficit; Surplus
  • H63 - Debt; Debt Management; Sovereign Debt
  • H68 - Forecasts of Budgets, Deficits, and Debt
  • Browse content in H7 - State and Local Government; Intergovernmental Relations
  • H70 - General
  • H74 - State and Local Borrowing
  • H77 - Intergovernmental Relations; Federalism; Secession
  • Browse content in I - Health, Education, and Welfare
  • Browse content in I0 - General
  • I00 - General
  • Browse content in I1 - Health
  • I10 - General
  • I12 - Health Behavior
  • I14 - Health and Inequality
  • I15 - Health and Economic Development
  • Browse content in I2 - Education and Research Institutions
  • I20 - General
  • I21 - Analysis of Education
  • I23 - Higher Education; Research Institutions
  • I24 - Education and Inequality
  • I26 - Returns to Education
  • Browse content in I3 - Welfare, Well-Being, and Poverty
  • I30 - General
  • I31 - General Welfare
  • I32 - Measurement and Analysis of Poverty
  • I38 - Government Policy; Provision and Effects of Welfare Programs
  • Browse content in J - Labor and Demographic Economics
  • Browse content in J0 - General
  • J00 - General
  • J01 - Labor Economics: General
  • J08 - Labor Economics Policies
  • Browse content in J1 - Demographic Economics
  • J10 - General
  • J13 - Fertility; Family Planning; Child Care; Children; Youth
  • J15 - Economics of Minorities, Races, Indigenous Peoples, and Immigrants; Non-labor Discrimination
  • J16 - Economics of Gender; Non-labor Discrimination
  • J18 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in J2 - Demand and Supply of Labor
  • J20 - General
  • J21 - Labor Force and Employment, Size, and Structure
  • J22 - Time Allocation and Labor Supply
  • J23 - Labor Demand
  • J24 - Human Capital; Skills; Occupational Choice; Labor Productivity
  • J26 - Retirement; Retirement Policies
  • J28 - Safety; Job Satisfaction; Related Public Policy
  • J29 - Other
  • Browse content in J3 - Wages, Compensation, and Labor Costs
  • J30 - General
  • J31 - Wage Level and Structure; Wage Differentials
  • J32 - Nonwage Labor Costs and Benefits; Retirement Plans; Private Pensions
  • J33 - Compensation Packages; Payment Methods
  • J38 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in J4 - Particular Labor Markets
  • J40 - General
  • J41 - Labor Contracts
  • J42 - Monopsony; Segmented Labor Markets
  • J44 - Professional Labor Markets; Occupational Licensing
  • J45 - Public Sector Labor Markets
  • J46 - Informal Labor Markets
  • J48 - Public Policy
  • J49 - Other
  • Browse content in J5 - Labor-Management Relations, Trade Unions, and Collective Bargaining
  • J50 - General
  • J51 - Trade Unions: Objectives, Structure, and Effects
  • J52 - Dispute Resolution: Strikes, Arbitration, and Mediation; Collective Bargaining
  • J53 - Labor-Management Relations; Industrial Jurisprudence
  • J54 - Producer Cooperatives; Labor Managed Firms; Employee Ownership
  • J58 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in J6 - Mobility, Unemployment, Vacancies, and Immigrant Workers
  • J60 - General
  • J61 - Geographic Labor Mobility; Immigrant Workers
  • J62 - Job, Occupational, and Intergenerational Mobility
  • J63 - Turnover; Vacancies; Layoffs
  • J64 - Unemployment: Models, Duration, Incidence, and Job Search
  • J65 - Unemployment Insurance; Severance Pay; Plant Closings
  • J68 - Public Policy
  • J69 - Other
  • Browse content in J7 - Labor Discrimination
  • J71 - Discrimination
  • J78 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in J8 - Labor Standards: National and International
  • J80 - General
  • J81 - Working Conditions
  • J83 - Workers' Rights
  • J88 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in K - Law and Economics
  • Browse content in K0 - General
  • K00 - General
  • Browse content in K1 - Basic Areas of Law
  • K11 - Property Law
  • K12 - Contract Law
  • K13 - Tort Law and Product Liability; Forensic Economics
  • Browse content in K2 - Regulation and Business Law
  • K20 - General
  • K21 - Antitrust Law
  • K22 - Business and Securities Law
  • K23 - Regulated Industries and Administrative Law
  • K25 - Real Estate Law
  • Browse content in K3 - Other Substantive Areas of Law
  • K31 - Labor Law
  • K39 - Other
  • Browse content in K4 - Legal Procedure, the Legal System, and Illegal Behavior
  • K40 - General
  • K41 - Litigation Process
  • K42 - Illegal Behavior and the Enforcement of Law
  • Browse content in L - Industrial Organization
  • Browse content in L0 - General
  • L00 - General
  • Browse content in L1 - Market Structure, Firm Strategy, and Market Performance
  • L10 - General
  • L11 - Production, Pricing, and Market Structure; Size Distribution of Firms
  • L12 - Monopoly; Monopolization Strategies
  • L13 - Oligopoly and Other Imperfect Markets
  • L14 - Transactional Relationships; Contracts and Reputation; Networks
  • L16 - Industrial Organization and Macroeconomics: Industrial Structure and Structural Change; Industrial Price Indices
  • Browse content in L2 - Firm Objectives, Organization, and Behavior
  • L20 - General
  • L21 - Business Objectives of the Firm
  • L22 - Firm Organization and Market Structure
  • L23 - Organization of Production
  • L24 - Contracting Out; Joint Ventures; Technology Licensing
  • L25 - Firm Performance: Size, Diversification, and Scope
  • L26 - Entrepreneurship
  • L29 - Other
  • Browse content in L3 - Nonprofit Organizations and Public Enterprise
  • L30 - General
  • L31 - Nonprofit Institutions; NGOs; Social Entrepreneurship
  • L32 - Public Enterprises; Public-Private Enterprises
  • L33 - Comparison of Public and Private Enterprises and Nonprofit Institutions; Privatization; Contracting Out
  • L39 - Other
  • Browse content in L4 - Antitrust Issues and Policies
  • L40 - General
  • L41 - Monopolization; Horizontal Anticompetitive Practices
  • L44 - Antitrust Policy and Public Enterprises, Nonprofit Institutions, and Professional Organizations
  • Browse content in L5 - Regulation and Industrial Policy
  • L50 - General
  • L52 - Industrial Policy; Sectoral Planning Methods
  • Browse content in L6 - Industry Studies: Manufacturing
  • L60 - General
  • L61 - Metals and Metal Products; Cement; Glass; Ceramics
  • L66 - Food; Beverages; Cosmetics; Tobacco; Wine and Spirits
  • L67 - Other Consumer Nondurables: Clothing, Textiles, Shoes, and Leather Goods; Household Goods; Sports Equipment
  • Browse content in L7 - Industry Studies: Primary Products and Construction
  • L78 - Government Policy
  • Browse content in L8 - Industry Studies: Services
  • L80 - General
  • L82 - Entertainment; Media
  • Browse content in L9 - Industry Studies: Transportation and Utilities
  • L97 - Utilities: General
  • L98 - Government Policy
  • Browse content in M - Business Administration and Business Economics; Marketing; Accounting; Personnel Economics
  • Browse content in M0 - General
  • M00 - General
  • Browse content in M1 - Business Administration
  • M10 - General
  • M12 - Personnel Management; Executives; Executive Compensation
  • M13 - New Firms; Startups
  • M16 - International Business Administration
  • Browse content in M2 - Business Economics
  • M21 - Business Economics
  • Browse content in M3 - Marketing and Advertising
  • M37 - Advertising
  • Browse content in M4 - Accounting and Auditing
  • M41 - Accounting
  • M49 - Other
  • Browse content in M5 - Personnel Economics
  • M51 - Firm Employment Decisions; Promotions
  • M52 - Compensation and Compensation Methods and Their Effects
  • M54 - Labor Management
  • M55 - Labor Contracting Devices
  • Browse content in N - Economic History
  • Browse content in N0 - General
  • N00 - General
  • N01 - Development of the Discipline: Historiographical; Sources and Methods
  • Browse content in N1 - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics; Industrial Structure; Growth; Fluctuations
  • N10 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N11 - U.S.; Canada: Pre-1913
  • N12 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • N13 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • N14 - Europe: 1913-
  • N15 - Asia including Middle East
  • N17 - Africa; Oceania
  • Browse content in N2 - Financial Markets and Institutions
  • N20 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N23 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • N24 - Europe: 1913-
  • N25 - Asia including Middle East
  • N26 - Latin America; Caribbean
  • Browse content in N3 - Labor and Consumers, Demography, Education, Health, Welfare, Income, Wealth, Religion, and Philanthropy
  • N30 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N32 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • N34 - Europe: 1913-
  • Browse content in N4 - Government, War, Law, International Relations, and Regulation
  • N43 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • Browse content in N5 - Agriculture, Natural Resources, Environment, and Extractive Industries
  • N50 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N51 - U.S.; Canada: Pre-1913
  • N52 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • N55 - Asia including Middle East
  • N7 - Transport, Trade, Energy, Technology, and Other Services
  • Browse content in N8 - Micro-Business History
  • N80 - General, International, or Comparative
  • Browse content in O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth
  • Browse content in O1 - Economic Development
  • O10 - General
  • O11 - Macroeconomic Analyses of Economic Development
  • O12 - Microeconomic Analyses of Economic Development
  • O13 - Agriculture; Natural Resources; Energy; Environment; Other Primary Products
  • O14 - Industrialization; Manufacturing and Service Industries; Choice of Technology
  • O15 - Human Resources; Human Development; Income Distribution; Migration
  • O16 - Financial Markets; Saving and Capital Investment; Corporate Finance and Governance
  • O17 - Formal and Informal Sectors; Shadow Economy; Institutional Arrangements
  • O18 - Urban, Rural, Regional, and Transportation Analysis; Housing; Infrastructure
  • O19 - International Linkages to Development; Role of International Organizations
  • Browse content in O2 - Development Planning and Policy
  • O20 - General
  • O23 - Fiscal and Monetary Policy in Development
  • O24 - Trade Policy; Factor Movement Policy; Foreign Exchange Policy
  • O25 - Industrial Policy
  • Browse content in O3 - Innovation; Research and Development; Technological Change; Intellectual Property Rights
  • O30 - General
  • O31 - Innovation and Invention: Processes and Incentives
  • O32 - Management of Technological Innovation and R&D
  • O33 - Technological Change: Choices and Consequences; Diffusion Processes
  • O34 - Intellectual Property and Intellectual Capital
  • O35 - Social Innovation
  • O38 - Government Policy
  • O39 - Other
  • Browse content in O4 - Economic Growth and Aggregate Productivity
  • O40 - General
  • O41 - One, Two, and Multisector Growth Models
  • O43 - Institutions and Growth
  • O44 - Environment and Growth
  • O47 - Empirical Studies of Economic Growth; Aggregate Productivity; Cross-Country Output Convergence
  • Browse content in O5 - Economywide Country Studies
  • O50 - General
  • O51 - U.S.; Canada
  • O52 - Europe
  • O53 - Asia including Middle East
  • O54 - Latin America; Caribbean
  • O55 - Africa
  • Browse content in P - Economic Systems
  • Browse content in P0 - General
  • P00 - General
  • Browse content in P1 - Capitalist Systems
  • P10 - General
  • P11 - Planning, Coordination, and Reform
  • P12 - Capitalist Enterprises
  • P13 - Cooperative Enterprises
  • P14 - Property Rights
  • P16 - Political Economy
  • P17 - Performance and Prospects
  • Browse content in P2 - Socialist Systems and Transitional Economies
  • P20 - General
  • P21 - Planning, Coordination, and Reform
  • P25 - Urban, Rural, and Regional Economics
  • Browse content in P3 - Socialist Institutions and Their Transitions
  • P30 - General
  • P31 - Socialist Enterprises and Their Transitions
  • P35 - Public Economics
  • P36 - Consumer Economics; Health; Education and Training; Welfare, Income, Wealth, and Poverty
  • P37 - Legal Institutions; Illegal Behavior
  • Browse content in P4 - Other Economic Systems
  • P40 - General
  • P41 - Planning, Coordination, and Reform
  • P46 - Consumer Economics; Health; Education and Training; Welfare, Income, Wealth, and Poverty
  • P48 - Political Economy; Legal Institutions; Property Rights; Natural Resources; Energy; Environment; Regional Studies
  • Browse content in P5 - Comparative Economic Systems
  • P50 - General
  • P51 - Comparative Analysis of Economic Systems
  • P52 - Comparative Studies of Particular Economies
  • Browse content in Q - Agricultural and Natural Resource Economics; Environmental and Ecological Economics
  • Browse content in Q0 - General
  • Q00 - General
  • Q01 - Sustainable Development
  • Browse content in Q1 - Agriculture
  • Q15 - Land Ownership and Tenure; Land Reform; Land Use; Irrigation; Agriculture and Environment
  • Q18 - Agricultural Policy; Food Policy
  • Browse content in Q3 - Nonrenewable Resources and Conservation
  • Q30 - General
  • Browse content in Q4 - Energy
  • Q41 - Demand and Supply; Prices
  • Q42 - Alternative Energy Sources
  • Q48 - Government Policy
  • Browse content in Q5 - Environmental Economics
  • Q50 - General
  • Q54 - Climate; Natural Disasters; Global Warming
  • Q56 - Environment and Development; Environment and Trade; Sustainability; Environmental Accounts and Accounting; Environmental Equity; Population Growth
  • Q57 - Ecological Economics: Ecosystem Services; Biodiversity Conservation; Bioeconomics; Industrial Ecology
  • Browse content in R - Urban, Rural, Regional, Real Estate, and Transportation Economics
  • Browse content in R0 - General
  • R00 - General
  • Browse content in R1 - General Regional Economics
  • R10 - General
  • R11 - Regional Economic Activity: Growth, Development, Environmental Issues, and Changes
  • R12 - Size and Spatial Distributions of Regional Economic Activity
  • R15 - Econometric and Input-Output Models; Other Models
  • Browse content in R2 - Household Analysis
  • R20 - General
  • Browse content in R3 - Real Estate Markets, Spatial Production Analysis, and Firm Location
  • R30 - General
  • R31 - Housing Supply and Markets
  • R4 - Transportation Economics
  • Browse content in R5 - Regional Government Analysis
  • R51 - Finance in Urban and Rural Economies
  • R58 - Regional Development Planning and Policy
  • Browse content in Y - Miscellaneous Categories
  • Browse content in Y1 - Data: Tables and Charts
  • Y10 - Data: Tables and Charts
  • Browse content in Y3 - Book Reviews (unclassified)
  • Y30 - Book Reviews (unclassified)
  • Browse content in Y8 - Related Disciplines
  • Y80 - Related Disciplines
  • Browse content in Z - Other Special Topics
  • Browse content in Z0 - General
  • Z00 - General
  • Browse content in Z1 - Cultural Economics; Economic Sociology; Economic Anthropology
  • Z10 - General
  • Z11 - Economics of the Arts and Literature
  • Z12 - Religion
  • Z13 - Economic Sociology; Economic Anthropology; Social and Economic Stratification
  • Z18 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in Z2 - Sports Economics
  • Z29 - Other
  • Advance articles
  • Editor's Choice
  • Author Guidelines
  • Submission Site
  • Open Access
  • About Cambridge Journal of Economics
  • About the Cambridge Political Economy Society
  • Editorial Board
  • Advertising and Corporate Services
  • Self-Archiving Policy
  • Dispatch Dates
  • Terms and Conditions
  • Journals on Oxford Academic
  • Books on Oxford Academic

Article Contents

1. introduction, 2. key structural flaws of the new financial architecture, 3. conclusion.

  • < Previous

Structural causes of the global financial crisis: a critical assessment of the ‘new financial architecture’

  • Article contents
  • Figures & tables
  • Supplementary Data

James Crotty, Structural causes of the global financial crisis: a critical assessment of the ‘new financial architecture’, Cambridge Journal of Economics , Volume 33, Issue 4, July 2009, Pages 563–580, https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/bep023

  • Permissions Icon Permissions

We are in the midst of the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression. This crisis is the latest phase of the evolution of financial markets under the radical financial deregulation process that began in the late 1970s. This evolution has taken the form of cycles in which deregulation accompanied by rapid financial innovation stimulates powerful financial booms that end in crises. Governments respond to crises with bailouts that allow new expansions to begin. As a result, financial markets have become ever larger and financial crises have become more threatening to society, which forces governments to enact ever larger bailouts. This process culminated in the current global financial crisis, which is so deeply rooted that even unprecedented interventions by affected governments have, thus far, failed to contain it. In this paper we analyse the structural flaws in the financial system that helped bring on the current crisis and discuss prospects for financial reform.

In the aftermath of the financial collapse in the USA that began in 1929, it was almost universally believed that unregulated financial markets are inherently unstable, subject to fraud and manipulation by insiders, and capable of triggering deep economic crises and political and social unrest. To protect the country from these dangers, in the mid 1930s the US government created a strict financial regulatory system that worked effectively through the 1960s. These economic and political events found reflection in the financial market theories of endogenous financial instability created by John Maynard Keynes and Hyman Minsky. Their theories generated a policy perspective supportive of the sharp shift from light to tight financial market regulation that took place after the Great Crash. Economic and financial turbulence in the 1970s and early 1980s led to both a paradigm and a policy regime shift. Efficient financial market theory and new classical macro theory replaced the theoretical visions of Keynes and Minsky, and the existing system of tight financial regulation was deconstructed through radical deregulation pushed by financial institutions and justified by efficient financial market theory. These developments facilitated the transition to a new globally-integrated deregulated neoliberal capitalism. 1

The main thesis of this paper is that, although problems in the US subprime mortgage market triggered the current financial crisis, its deep cause on the financial side is to be found in the flawed institutions and practices of the current financial regime, often referred to as the New Financial Architecture (NFA). (While the global crisis clearly has both financial- and real-sector roots, this paper deals primarily with the former.) ‘New Financial Architecture’ refers to the integration of modern day financial markets with the era's light government regulation. After 1980, accelerated deregulation accompanied by rapid financial innovation stimulated powerful financial booms that always ended in crises. Governments responded with bailouts that allowed new expansions to begin. These in turn ended in crises, which triggered new bailouts. Over time, financial markets grew ever larger relative to the nonfinancial economy, important financial products became more complex, opaque and illiquid, and system-wide leverage exploded. As a result, financial crises became more threatening. This process culminated in the current crisis, which is so severe that it has pushed the global economy to the brink of depression. Fear of financial and economic collapse has induced unprecedented government rescue efforts that have been, to date, unable to end the crisis. In the next section of the paper we present a description of key structural flaws in the financial institutions and practices of the neoliberal era that helped generate the current crisis. This section is taken from a much more detailed analysis of these structural flaws (see Crotty, 2008 ).

2.1 The NFA is built on a very weak theoretical foundation

The NFA is based on light regulation of commercial banks, even lighter regulation of investment banks and little, if any, regulation of the ‘shadow banking system’—hedge and private equity funds and bank-created Special Investment Vehicles (SIVs). Support for lax regulation was reinforced by the central claim of neoclassical financial economics that capital markets price securities correctly with respect to expected risk and return. Buyers and sellers of financial securities were, it was argued, able to make optimal decisions that led to risk being held only by those capable of managing it. The celebratory narrative associated with the NFA states that relatively free financial markets minimise the possibility of financial crises and the need for government bailouts (see Volcker, 2008, for a summary of this narrative). Crotty (2008) explains that this theoretical cornerstone of the NFA is based on patently unrealistic assumptions and has no convincing empirical support. Thus, the ‘scientific’ foundation of the NFA is shockingly weak and its celebratory narrative is a fairy tale.

2.2 The NFA has widespread perverse incentives that create excessive risk, exacerbate booms and generate crises

The current financial system is riddled with perverse incentives that induce key personnel in virtually all important financial institutions—including commercial and investment banks, hedge and private equity funds, insurance companies and mutual and pension funds—to take excessive risk when financial markets are buoyant. 2 For example, the growth of mortgage securitisation generated fee income—to banks and mortgage brokers who sold the loans, investment bankers who packaged the loans into securities, banks and specialist institutions who serviced the securities and ratings agencies who gave them their seal of approval. Since fees do not have to be returned if the securities later suffer large losses, everyone involved had strong incentives to maximise the flow of loans through the system whether or not they were sound. Total fees from home sales and mortgage securitisation from 2003 to 2008 have been estimated at $2 trillion ( Financial Times , 2008C ).

Top investment bank traders and executives receive giant bonuses in years in which risk-taking generates high revenue and profits. Of course, profits and bonuses are maximised in the boom by maximising leverage, which in turn maximises risk. In 2006, Goldman Sachs’ bonus pool totaled $16 billion—an average bonus of $650,000 very unequally distributed across Goldman's 25,000 employees. Wall Street's top traders received bonuses of up to $50 million that year. In spite of the investment bank disasters of the second half of 2007, which saw Wall Street investment banks lose over $11 billion, the average bonus fell only 4.7%. In 2008 losses skyrocketed causing the five largest independent investment banks to lose their independence: two failed, one was taken over by a conglomerate, and two became bank holding companies to qualify them for bailout money. Yet Wall Street bonuses were over $18 billion—about what they were in the boom year of 2004 ( DiNapoli, 2009 ). Bonuses at Goldman are expected to average $570,000 in 2009 in the midst of the crisis ( New York Times , 2009F).

About 700 employees of Merrill Lynch received bonuses in excess of $1 million in 2008 from a total bonus pool of $3.6 billion, in spite of the fact that the firm lost $27 billion. The top four recipients alone received a total of $121 million while the top 14 got $249 million ( Wall Street Journal , 2009A ). Losses reported by Merrill totaled $35.8 billion in 2007 and 2008, enough to wipe out 11 years of earnings previously reported by the company. Yet for the 11-year period from 1997 to 2008, Merrill's board gave its chief executives alone more than $240 million in performance-based compensation ( New York Times , 2009A ).

One of the most egregious examples of perverse incentives can be found in insurance giant AIG's Financial Products unit. This division, which gambled on credit default swaps (CDSs), contributed substantially to AIG's rising profits in the boom. In 2008 the unit lost $40.5 billion. Though the US government owns 80% of AIG's shares and invested $180 billion in the corporation, AIG nevertheless paid the 377 members of the division a total of $220 million in bonuses for 2008, an average of over $500,000 per employee. Seven employees received more than $3 million each ( Wall Street Journal , 2009C ).

These examples show that it is rational for top financial firm operatives to take excessive risk in the bubble even if they understand that their decisions are likely to cause a crash in the intermediate future. Since they do not have to return their bubble-year bonuses when the inevitable crisis occurs and since they continue to receive substantial bonuses even in the crisis, they have a powerful incentive to pursue high-risk, high-leverage strategies.

Credit rating agencies were also infected by perverse incentives. Under Basle I rules, banks were required to hold 8% of core or tier-one capital against their total risk-weighted assets. Since ratings agencies determined the risk weights on many assets, they strongly influenced bank capital requirements. Under Basle II rules banks only needed a modest sliver of capital to support triple-A securities. High ratings thus meant less required capital, higher leverage, higher profit and higher bonuses. Moreover, important financial institutions are not permitted to hold assets with less than an AAA rating from one of the major rating companies. There was thus a strong demand for high ratings. Ratings agencies are paid by the investment banks whose products they rate. Their profits therefore depend on whether they keep these banks happy. In 2005, more than 40% of Moody's revenue came from rating securitised debt such as mortgage backed securities (MBSs) and collateralised debt obligations (CDOs). If one agency gave realistic assessments of the high risk associated with these securities while others did not, that firm would see its profit plummet. Thus, it made sense for investment banks to shop their securities around, looking for the agency that would give them the highest ratings, and it made sense for agencies to provide excessively optimistic ratings. 3 The recent global financial boom and crisis might not have occurred if perverse incentives had not induced credit rating agencies to give absurdly high ratings to illiquid, non-transparent, structured financial products such as MBSs, CDOs and collateralized loan obligations. 4

Reregulation of financial markets will not be effective unless it substantially reduces the perverse incentives that pervade the system.

2.3 Innovation created important financial products so complex and opaque they could not be priced correctly; they therefore lost liquidity when the boom ended

Financial innovation has proceeded to the point where important structured financial products are so complex that they are inherently non-transparent. They cannot be priced correctly, are not sold on markets and are illiquid. According to the Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association (SIFMA), there was $7.4 trillion worth of MBSs outstanding in the first quarter of 2008, more than double the amount outstanding in 2001. Over $500 billion dollars in CDOs were issued in both 2006 and 2007, up from $157 billion as recently as 2004 (SIFMA website). The explosion of these securities created large profits at giant financial institutions, but also destroyed the transparency necessary for any semblance of market efficiency. Indeed, the value of securities not sold on markets may exceed the value of securities that are. Eighty percent of the world's $680 trillion worth of derivatives are sold over-the-counter in private deals negotiated between an investment bank and one or more customers. Thus, the claim that competitive capital markets price risk optimally, which is the foundation of the NFA, does not apply even in principle to these securities.

Even with a mathematical approach to handling correlation, the complexity of calculating the expected default payment, which is what is needed to arrive at a CDO price, grows exponentially with an increasing number of reference assets [the original mortgages]… . As it turns out, it is hard to derive a generalized model or formula that handles this complex calculation while still being practical to use. ( Chacko et al. , 2006 , p. 226)

The relation between the value of a CDO and the value of its mortgages is complex and nonlinear. Significant changes in the value of underlying mortgages induce large and unpredictable movements in CDO values. Ratings agencies and the investment banks that create these securities rely on extremely complicated simulation models to price them. It can take a powerful computer several days to determine the price of a CDO. These models are unreliable and easily manipulated statistical black boxes. Given perverse incentives, it is not surprising that market insiders refer to the process through which CDOs are marked or priced as marking to ‘magic’ or to ‘myth’. New York University's Nouriel Roubini observed that CDOs ‘were new, exotic, complex, illiquid, marked-to-model rather than marked-to-market and misrated by the rating agencies. Who could then ever be able to correctly price or value a CDO cubed?’ ( Roubini, 2008 ).

Demand for CDOs was strong in the boom because buyers could borrow money cheaply, returns were high and the products carried top ratings. But when the housing boom ended and defaults increased, the fact that no one knew what these securities were worth caused demand and liquidity to evaporate and prices to plummet. The celebratory narrative of the NFA had assured investors this could not happen. Efficient market theory asserts that liquidity will always be available to support security prices. Charles Goodhart, former member of the Bank of England's Monetary Policy Committee, noted that the theory assured investors ‘that you can always obtain funding to hold assets … and that the … short-term wholesale market, the interbank markets, the asset-backed commercial paper market and so on, would always be open and you would always have access to them’ ( Goodhart, 2009 ). Yet when the crisis hit, CDOs could be sold, if at all, only at an enormous loss. It is estimated that by February 2009, almost half of all the CDOs ever issued had defaulted ( Financial Times , 2009B ). Defaults led to a 32% drop in the value of triple A rated CDOs composed of super-safe senior tranches and a 95% loss on triple A rated CDOs composed of mezzanine tranches ( Financial Times , 2007A ).

Innovation became so intense that it outran the comprehension of most ordinary bankers—not to mention regulators. As a result, not only is the financial system plagued with losses on a scale that nobody foresaw, but the pillars of faith on which this new financial capitalism were built have all but collapsed. ( Tett, 2009 )

2.4 The claim that commercial banks distributed almost all risky assets to capital markets and hedged whatever risk remained was false

The conventional view was that banks were not risky because, in contrast to the previous era when they held the loans they made, they now sold their loans to capital markets through securitisation in the new ‘originate and distribute’ banking model. Moreover, it was believed that banks hedged whatever risk remained through CDSs. Both these propositions turned out to be false. Banks kept risky products such as MBSs and CDOs for five reasons, none of which were considered in the NFA narrative about efficient capital markets.

First, to reduce moral hazard and convince potential investors that these securities were safe, banks often had to retain the riskiest part—the so-called ‘toxic waste’.

Second, CDOs were especially attractive assets for banks to keep since they could be held off-balance-sheet with no capital reserve requirements , a development discussed below.

Third, the rate of flow of these securities through banks was so great and the time lapse between a bank's receipt of a mortgage and the sale of the MBS or CDO of which it was a part was sufficiently long that at every point in time banks held or ‘warehoused’ substantial quantities of these securities. When demand for MBSs and CDOs collapsed, banks were left holding huge amounts of mortgages and mortgage-backed products they could not sell. Global CDO issuance fell from $177 billion in the first quarter of 2007 to less than $20 billion one year later, a drop of 84%. The collapse in the price of these products is the main source of the massive bank losses that are the driving force of the crisis.

Merrill Lynch was one of the two largest underwriters of CDOs in the 3 years leading up to the crisis. While Merrill Lynch had only $3.4 billion in CDO origination in 2003, in 2006 it posted $44 billion in CDO deals. Merrill's rainmakers became addicted to the fees that flowed from financing CDOs, which reached $700 million in 2006.

Merrill apparently made a pivotal—and reckless—decision. It bought big swaths of the AAA paper itself, loading the debt onto its own books… . The amounts were staggering. By the end of June, Merrill held $41 billion in subprime CDOs and subprime mortgage bonds. Since the average deal is between $1 billion and $1.5 billion, and the AAA debt is around 80% of each deal, Merrill must have been buying nearly all the top-rated debt from dozens of CDOs… . Merrill's $41 billion exposure to subprime paper was more than its entire shareholders’ equity of $38 billion. That this huge position went unhedged astonishes everyone on Wall Street… ( Fortune Magazine , 2007 , emphasis added). 5

Fourth, when banks found the safest or ‘super senior’ tranches of mortgage backed securities hard to sell because their yield was relatively low, they kept them themselves so that they could sustain the high rate of CDO sales that kept bonuses rising. In a comment about this practice that reflects both the power of perverse incentives and the destructive dimensions of financial market competition, Citigroup CEO Charles Prince said in July 2007: ‘When the music stops, in terms of liquidity, things will be complicated. But as long as the music is playing, you've got to get up and dance. We're still dancing’ ( Financial Times , 2007C ).

Fifth, given banks’ incentive to generate high profits and bonuses through high risk, they purposely kept some of the riskiest products they created.

In 2007, the Bank of England called attention to the fact that large global banks were not slimming down as the ‘originate-and-distribute model’ predicted they would. Rather, on-balance-sheet assets had exploded from $10 trillion in 2000 to $23 trillion in 2006. The main cause of this asset growth was the incredible rise in bank holdings of MBSs and CDOs, the kinds of securities that banks were supposed to sell rather than hold in the narrative of the NFA. In April 2009, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) estimated potential losses in 2007–2010 from US-originated credit assets held by banks and others at $2.7 trillion ( IMF, 2009 , p. 27). Richardson and Roubini ‘suggest that total losses on loans made by U.S. banks and the fall in the market value of the assets they are holding will reach about $3.6 trillion. The U.S. banking sector is exposed to half that figure, or $1.8 trillion’ ( Richardson and Roubini, 2009 ).

Claims that banks hedged most risk through CDSs were equally shaky. Credit default swaps are derivatives that allow one party to insure against loss from loan defaults by paying insurance fees to another party. However, since the value of credit default swaps hit $62 trillion in December 2007, while the maximum value of debt that might conceivably be insured through these derivatives was $5 trillion, it was evident that massive speculation by banks and others was taking place. Fitch Ratings reported that 58% of banks that buy and sell credit derivatives acknowledged that ‘trading’ or gambling is their ‘dominant’ motivation for operating in this market, whereas less than 30% said that ‘hedging/credit risk management’ was their primary motive. This ‘confirms the transition of credit derivatives from a hedging vehicle to primarily another trading asset class’ ( FitchRatings , 2007 , p. 9). Eric Dinallo, the insurance superintendent for New York State, said that 80% of the estimated $62 trillion in CDSs outstanding in 2008 were speculative ( New York Times , 2009D ).

By 2007 the CDS market had turned into a gambling casino that eventually helped destroy insurance giant AIG and investment banks Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers. As of February 2009 AIG alone had suffered losses of over $60 billion on CDS contracts ( Haldane, 2009 , p. 14.) No regulator objected when AIG guaranteed $440 billion worth of shaky securities with no capital set aside to protect against loss apparently because both the securities and AIG were triple A rated. The bonus-drenched ‘geniuses at A.I.G. who wrote the insurance were willing to bet more than double their company's value that defaults would not become problematic’ ( New York Times , 2009C ). A major reason that the government invested $180 billion to save AIG was to provide protection against losses that large US and foreign institutions would have incurred from their contracts with AIG had the company folded. Goldman Sachs received $12.9 billion and Merrill Lynch $7 billion, while 20 European banks received a total of $59 billion of US taxpayer money ( New York Times , 2009E ). This reflects moral hazard of the highest order. Firms like Goldman could gamble with confidence on risky CDOs only because they bought insurance from risk-laden AIG, who they knew was drastically under-capitalised. When they lost their bet on AIG, the public was forced to pay the bill because former Goldman Chief Executive Henry Paulson, acting in his capacity as Secretary of the Treasury, decided to rescue AIG even though he had previously let Lehman Brothers default (Paulson had to have known that Goldman would receive billions of dollars as the result of his decision). Though CDO prices had plunged, the government inexplicably paid banks their full face value. The regulators thus allowed the dominant financial firms and their top bonus recipients to engage in publicly subsidised win–win gambles.

Securitisation and the rise of CDSs did raise big-bank profits for many years, but they eventually created huge losses that more than wiped out the cumulative gains made over the long boom. As early as December 2007, Citigroup had ‘lost more money than it made from financial instruments based on U.S. subprime mortgages…’ ( Bloomberg , 2007 ).

2.5 Regulators allowed banks to hold assets off balance sheet with no capital required to support them

In the late 1990s, banks were allowed to hold risky securities off their balance sheets in SIVs with no capital required to support them. The regulatory system thus induced banks to move as much of their assets off-balance-sheet as possible. When the demand for risky financial products cooled off in mid 2007, bank-created off-balance-sheet SIVs became the buyer of last resort for the ocean of new MBSs and CDOs emanating from investment banks. At the end of 2007, J.P. Morgan Chase & Co. and Citigroup each had nearly $1 trillion in assets held off their books in special securitisation vehicles. For Citigroup this represented about half the bank's overall assets. ( Wall Street Journal , 2008 ). 7

SIVs were supposed to be stand-alone institutions that paid service fees to the originating banks, but to which the originating banks had no obligations or commitments. They borrowed short-term in the commercial paper market and used this money to buy long-term, illiquid but highly profitable securities such as CDOs—a very dangerous game. To enable this commercial paper to receive AAA ratings and thus low interest rates, originating banks had to provide their SIVs with guaranteed lines of credit. This made the banks vulnerable to problems experienced by their supposedly independent SIVs.

When problems in the housing market triggered a wave of subprime defaults, the value of MBSs and CDOs collapsed. This triggered a mass exodus from the asset-backed commercial paper market. US asset-backed commercial paper outstanding fell from $1.2 trillion in July 2007 to $840 billion by the year's end. With the disappearance of their major source of funding, banks were forced to move these damaged assets to their balance sheets. In late July 2008 analysts at Citigroup forecast that up to $5 trillion worth of assets might be forced back on to bank balance sheets ( Financial Times , 2008B ). Contrary to the assumed transparency of financial markets, until SIVs began to collapse very few experienced financial market professionals knew they existed. ‘“In spite of more than 30 years in the business, I was unaware of the extent of banks’ off-balance-sheet vehicles such as SIVs” Anthony Bolton, president of investments at Fidelity International, recently observed’ ( Tett, 2009 ).

The combination of bank write downs on assets held on-balance-sheet combined with devalued SIV assets that had to be moved back onto balance sheets severely eroded bank capital. This in turn forced banks to try to lower their risk by raising interest rates and cutting loans to other financial institutions and to households and nonfinancial businesses.

2.6 Regulators allowed giant banks to measure their own risk and set their own capital requirements. Given perverse incentives, this inevitably led to excessive risk-taking

Deregulation allowed financial conglomerates to become so large and complex that neither insiders nor outsiders could accurately evaluate their risk. The Bank for International Settlement told national regulators to allow banks to evaluate their own risk—and thus set their own capital requirements—through a statistical exercise based on historical data called Value at Risk (VAR). Government officials thus ceded to banks, as they had to ratings agencies, crucial aspects of regulatory power. VAR is an estimate of the highest possible loss in the value of a portfolio of securities over a fixed time interval with a specific statistical confidence level. The standard exercise calculates VAR under negative conditions likely to occur less than 5% of the time.

There are four fundamental flaws in this mode of risk assessment. First, there is no time period in which historical data can be used to generate a reliable estimate of current risk. If firms use data from the past year or less, as is standard practice, then during boom periods such as 2003 to mid 2007 VAR exercises will show that risk is minimal because defaults and capital losses on securities are low. Banks thus need to set aside only a small amount of capital against estimated risk, which allows them to aggressively expand leverage, which in turn accelerates security price increases. The chairman of the UK's Financial Services Authority said that VAR ‘fails to allow for the fact that historically low volatility may actually be an indication of irrationally low risk-aversion and therefore increased systemic risk’ ( Financial Time s, 2009A ). On the other hand, if data from past decades are used, the existence of past crises will raise estimated risk, but financial markets will have undergone such fundamental change that these estimates will bear no relation whatever to current risk.

Second, VAR models assume that security prices are generated by a normal distribution. In a normal distribution the likelihood that an observation many standard deviations beyond a 95% or even a 99% confidence interval will occur is infinitesimal. In fact, security prices follow a distribution in which the preponderance of observations are ‘normal’, but every five to ten years observations occur that are so far from the mean that they are virtually incompatible with the assumption of a normal distribution. Examples of this well-known ‘fat tail’ phenomenon include the precipitous drop in stock prices that took place in August 1987, the global crisis brought on by the collapse of the giant hedge fund Long Term Capital Management, the Asian crisis and the recent global stock market and CDO crash. In August 2007, two large hedge funds managed by Goldman Sachs collapsed, forcing Goldman to inject $3 billion into the funds. To explain why Goldman should not be held responsible for their collapse, chief financial officer David Viniar said ‘We were seeing things that were 25 standard deviation moves, several days in a row’ ( Financial Times , 2007B , p. 25). The Director for Financial Stability of the Bank of England noted that, under a normal distribution, ‘a 25-sigma event would be expected to occur once every 6×10 124 lives of the universe’ adding, tongue-in-cheek, that when he tried to calculate the probability of such an event occurring several days in a row, ‘the lights visibly dimmed over London’. Even a 7.3 standard deviation event should occur only once every 13 billion years ( Haldane, 2009 , p. 2). Allowing banks to estimate risk and set capital requirements on the assumption that large losses cannot happen left them vulnerable when the crisis erupted.

Third, the asset-price correlation matrix is a key determinant of measured VAR. The lower the correlation among security prices, the lower the portfolio's risk. VAR models assume that future asset price correlations will be similar to those of the recent past. However, in crises the historical correlation matrix loses all relation to actual asset price dynamics. Most prices fall together as investors run for liquidity and safety, and correlations invariably head toward one, as they did in the recent crisis. Again, actual risk is much higher than risk estimates from VAR exercises.

Fourth, the trillions of dollars in assets held off balance sheet were not included in VAR calculations ( Blankfein, 2009 ).

Reliance on VAR helped create the current crisis and left banks with woefully inadequate capital reserves when it broke out. A Financial Times editorial observed that ‘risk management models … were catastrophic’ ( Financial Times , 2008D ). The Financial Time ’s Gillian Tett concluded that ‘it was sheer madness for financiers ever to have relied so heavily on these VAR models during the first seven years of this decade’ ( Tett, 2008B ). VAR-determined capital requirement are just one of many possible examples of totally ineffective regulatory processes within the NFA. Financial markets were not just lightly regulated, such regulation as did exist was often ‘phantom’ regulation—ineffective by design.

The problems involved in risk management through VAR were apparent to everyone who understood even the outline of the procedure; you do not need specialist knowledge to spot them. I explained the problems associated with VAR in Crotty, 2007 , a paper written in 2006, well before the crisis developed. Yet only a few influential financial observers warned against the futility of standard risk management practices prior to the crisis because VAR-based risk assessment maximised bonuses. No one wanted to kill the goose that was laying golden eggs.

VAR was dangerous. It gave firms a false sense of complacency, because it ignored certain risks and relied heavily on past price movements. In some markets, VAR actually increased risk, because every trader assessed risk in the same flawed way. In other markets, traders [using different VAR models] calculated VAR measures that varied ‘by 14 times or more.’ … LTMC's VAR models had predicted that the fund's maximum daily loss would be in the tens of millions of dollars, and that it would not have collapsed in the lifetime of several billion universes. ( Partnoy, 2003 , p. 263)

2.7 Heavy reliance on complex financial products in a tightly integrated global financial system created channels of contagion that raised systemic risk

It was claimed that in the NFA, complex derivatives would allow the risk associated with securities to be divided into its component parts, such as interest rate and counter-party risk. Investors could buy only those risk segments they felt comfortable holding. And rather than concentrate in banks as in the ‘Golden Age’ financial system, it was argued, risk would be lightly sprinkled on agents all across the globe. Since markets price risk correctly, no one would be fooled into holding excessive risk, so systemic risk would be minimised. Then New York Fed Chairman, and current Secretary of the Treasury, Timothy Geithner stated in 2006: ‘In the financial system we have today, with less risk concentrated in banks, the probability of systemic financial crises may be lower than in traditional bank-centered financial systems’ ( Geithner, 2008 ). In 2006 the IMF proclaimed that the dispersion of credit risk ‘has helped to make the banking and overall financial system more resilient’ ( Tett, 2009 ).

There are major flaws in this argument. As Financial Times columnist Martin Wolf put it: ‘The proposition that sophisticated modern finance was able to transfer risk to those best able to manage it has failed. The paradigm is, instead, that risk has been transferred to those least able to understand it’ ( Wolf, 2009 ). First, and perhaps most important, it implicitly assumed that the NFA would not generate more total risk than the previous tightly-regulated bank-based regime, but only spread a given system-wide risk across more investors. However, the degree of system-wide risk associated with any financial regime is endogenous. The effect of regime change on systemic risk depends on the amount of real and financial risk it creates and the way it disperses that risk, factors strongly affected by the mode of regulation. The structure of the NFA inevitably created excessive risk.

Second, derivatives can be used to speculate as well as to hedge. In the boom, hedging via derivatives is relatively inexpensive, but financial institutions guided by perverse incentives do not want to accept the deductions from profit and the bonus pool that full hedging entails. ‘Why financial institutions don't hedge risk more adequately is no mystery. It … costs money and cuts into returns—and, of course, their fees’ ( Wall Street Journal , 2007A ). Conversely, after serious trouble hits financial markets, agents would like to hedge risk, but the cost becomes prohibitive. For example, to insure $10 million of Citigroup debt against default for 5 years through CDSs cost about $15,000 a year in May 2007, but $190,000 in February 2008. Moreover, a rise in the cost of hedging can occur quickly and unexpectedly. The cost of insuring Countrywide debt rose from $75,000 in early July 2007 to $230,000 one month later; it then jumped by $120,000 in just one day ( Wall Street Journal , 2007B ). By January 2008, the cost of insuring Countrywide's debt was $3 million up front and $500,000 annually.

Ironically, while the ability to hedge via derivatives can make an individual investor safer, it can simultaneously make the system riskier. For example, hedging often involves dynamic derivative trading strategies that rely on liquid continuous markets with low to moderate transactions costs. A typical dynamic hedge involves shorting the risky asset held and investing in a risk-free asset. The hedge adjusts whenever the asset price, interest rate or volatility changes, which they do continuously. Every time the asset price declines or volatility increases, the risky asset must be sold; this is what makes the hedge ‘dynamic’. When problems hit, price falls and volatility rises. Institutions with dynamic hedges must sell their risky assets, which accelerates the rate of price decrease, which in turn forces more hedged-asset sales. If many investors have made similar dynamic hedges and are selling, liquidity dries up and prices can free-fall.

Consider the role played by AIG in the exploding CDS market. Many institutions used CDSs to hedge against a loss in the value of their CDOs (one reason banks bought CDS protection is that it lowered their capital requirements). Insurers such as AIG piled up immense commitments to pay in the event of defaults or capital losses with little capital to back these commitments. When losses hit security markets AIG could not pay off its contracts; it became insolvent. 8 Had the government not put $180 billion into AIG, many large financial institutions around the world would have failed. Ultimately, CDSs made the system more fragile because they facilitated excessive risk-taking.

Third, the narrative insists that derivatives unbundle risk, dividing it into simpler segments. But in fact, sophisticated derivatives such as CDOs re-bundle risk in the most complicated and non-transparent ways: this is what financial engineering and structured derivative products do. 9 These derivatives also add substantial ‘embedded’ leverage to the underlying or primitive products to enhance investor profits. Das explains how layers of unseen leverage added to derivative products by investment bankers sold to Orange County California caused unforeseen catastrophic losses: ‘Greenspan had been right—risk had truly been unbundled. We had packaged it right back up and shoved it down the eager throats of the wealthy taxpayers of Orange County’ ( Das, 2006 , p. 50).

Fourth, the celebratory NFA narrative applauded globalisation of financial markets because it created channels of risk dispersion. But securitisation and funding via tightly integrated global capital markets simultaneously created channels of contagion in which a crisis that originated in one product in one location (US subprime mortgages) quickly spread to other products (US prime mortgages, MBSs, CDOs, home equity loans, loans to residential construction companies, credit cards, auto loans, monoline insurance and auction rate securities) and throughout the world. The complexity of the networks linking markets together created immense fragility in the system: ‘Complexity adds to the danger that any one part of the hyper-financial system can bring down the whole’ ( Financial Times , 2008A ).

New and complex instruments to transfer credit risks in combination with large banks engaging in an ‘originate and distribute’ business model have amplified the consequences of the undeniable excesses in the US mortgage market … In the end, the new instruments of credit risk-transfer distributed fear instead of risk. ( Weber, 2008 )

2.8 The NFA facilitated the growth of dangerously high system-wide leverage

As noted, structural flaws in the NFA created dangerous leverage throughout the financial system. Annual borrowing by US financial institutions as a percent of gross domestic product (GDP) jumped from 6.9% in 1997 to 12.8% a decade later.

From 1975 to 2003, the US Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) limited investment bank leverage to 12 times capital. However, in 2004, under pressure from Goldman Sachs chairman and later Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson, it raised the acceptable leverage ratio to 40 times capital and made compliance voluntary ( Wall Street Watch , 2009 , p. 17). This allowed large investment banks to generate asset-to-equity ratios in the mid to upper 30s just before the crisis, with at least half of their borrowing in the form of overnight repos, money that could flee at the first hint of trouble. 10 With leverage rates this high, any serious fall in asset prices would trigger a dangerous deleveraging dynamic.

Commercial banks appeared to be adequately capitalised, but only because they over-estimated the value of on-balance-sheet assets while holding a high percentage of their most vulnerable assets hidden off-balance-sheet. In fact, they were excessively leveraged, as the crisis revealed. Many European banks had leverage ratios of 50 or more before the crisis ( Goodhart, 2009 ), while Citibank's and Bank of America's ratios were even higher ( Ferguson, 2008 ). By the end of 2008 many large banks had seen their equity position evaporate to the brink of insolvency and beyond. Only massive government bailouts kept these ‘zombie banks’ alive.

Rising leverage was facilitated in part by the easy money policies of the Fed. To avoid a deep financial crisis following the collapse of the late 1990s stock market and internet booms, the Fed began to cut short-term interest rates in late 2000 and continued to hold them at record lows through to mid-2004. Financial firms were thus able to borrow cheaply, which, under different circumstances, might have fueled a boom in productive capital investment. However, given perverse incentives in financial markets, the spectacular returns to financial risk-taking, and a sluggish real economy in which growth was sustained primarily through the impact of rising debt and financial wealth on aggregate demand, the additional funds were mostly used for speculative financial investment.

Increased leverage helped push the size of financial markets to unsustainable heights relative to the real economy. By 2007 the global financial system had become, to use Hyman Minsky's famous phrase, ‘financially fragile’. The term is usually applied to a cycle phase, but in this case the condition had become secular. Any serious deterioration in the cash flows required to sustain security prices could have triggered a dangerous de-leveraging process. Falling housing prices and rising mortgage defaults provided that trigger. By January 2009, housing prices had declined by almost 28% according to the Case–Shiller index and mortgage default rates rose steadily. Structured financial security price declines were stunning. One reason was that: ‘The leverage used to put [CDOs] together can amplify losses [in the downturn]. For example, a 4 percent loss in a mortgage backed security held by collateralized debt obligations can turn into almost a 40% loss to the holder of the CDO itself’ ( New York Times , 2007 ). New York Fed Chairman Timothy Geithner expressed concern about the destructive power of reverse leverage in May 2007: ‘As market participants move to protect themselves against further losses, by selling positions, requiring more margin, hedging against further declines, the shock is amplified and the brake becomes the accelerator’ ( Geithner, 2008 ).

The downward spiral was exacerbated by the role ratings agencies played in the regulatory system. Facing a wave of criticism for having led investors astray in the boom with overly optimistic ratings, agencies belatedly shifted assets to higher-risk categories in the crisis. A small rating downgrade can lead to a large increase in required capital; the relation is not linear. Banks therefore had to come up with more capital to support their assets. Banks were thus forced to sell assets into a collapsing market. Meanwhile, margin calls forced borrowers to sell securities. The de-leveraging process froze credit markets. Since modern nonfinancial business and household sectors run on credit, the shrinking availability and rising cost of borrowing led to a slowdown in economic growth that in turn worsened the global financial crisis. The NFA had finally brought the global economy to the edge of the abyss.

The past quarter century of deregulation and the globalisation of financial markets, combined with the rapid pace of financial innovation and the moral hazard caused by frequent government bailouts helped create conditions that led to this devastating financial crisis. The severity of the global financial crisis and the global economic recession that accompanied it demonstrate the utter bankruptcy of the deregulated global neoliberal financial system and the market fundamentalism it reflects. Many of its most influential supporters, including Alan Greenspan, have recanted. Senior Financial Times columnist Martin Wolf recently wrote: ‘The era of financial liberalisation has ended’ ( Wolf, 2009 ).

Several decades of deregulation and innovation grossly inflated the size of financial markets relative to the real economy. The value of all financial assets in the US grew from four times GDP in 1980 to ten times GDP in 2007. In 1981 household debt was 48% of GDP, while in 2007 it was 100%. Private sector debt was 123% of GDP in 1981 and 290% by late 2008. The financial sector has been in a leveraging frenzy: its debt rose from 22% of GDP in 1981 to 117% in late 2008. The share of corporate profits generated in the financial sector rose from 10% in the early 1980s to 40% in 2006, while its share of the stock market's value grew from 6% to 23%.

The scope and severity of the current crisis is a clear signal that the growth trajectory of financial markets in recent decades is unsustainable and must be reversed . It is not possible for the value of financial assets to remain so large relative to the real economy because the real economy cannot consistently generate the cash flows required to sustain such inflated financial claims. It is not economically efficient to have such large proportions of income and human and material resources captured by the financial sector. 11 Financial markets must be forced to shrink substantially relative to nonfinancial sectors, a process already initiated by the crisis, and the nontransparent, illiquid, complex securities that helped cause the financial collapse must be marginalised or banned.

Governments thus face a daunting challenge: they have to stop the financial collapse in the short run to prevent a global depression, while orchestrating a major overhaul and contraction of financial markets over the longer run . The US economy is especially vulnerable because growth over the past few decades has been driven largely by rising household spending on consumption and residential investment. Consumption as a percent of GDP was 63% in 1980, 67% in 1998 and 70% in 2008. Since real wages were stagnant and real family income growth was slow, rising household spending was increasingly driven by the combined effects of rising debt and the increase in household wealth created by stock market and housing booms. Household debt was 48% of GDP in 1985, about where it had been in 1965. But it grew to 66% by 1998, then accelerated to over 100% by late 2008.

This dynamic process has reversed direction in the crisis. The saving rate is rising rapidly as households repay debt and attempt to rebuild wealth to create a cushion against job and income loss. Meanwhile, wealth is evaporating. Stock and residential housing values in the US have dropped by more than a combined $15 trillion, a 24% decline from the 2007 peak of $64 trillion. 12 According to Robert Solow, as a result of these developments ‘we are looking at a potential drop in consumer spending of something like $650 billion a year’, which is far larger than the annual impact of President Obama's fiscal stimulus package ( Solow, 2009 ). Falling wealth along with deteriorating labour market conditions and declining business investment spending have caused aggregate demand to collapse. Governments have been wise to use public funds as a partial counterweight to the impact of falling private spending on aggregate demand. Indeed, more needs to be done in this regard. It was also sensible to use public money to slow the rate of financial collapse, though the US government in particular has been spectacularly inefficient in its financial intervention policies.

The financial-services industry is condemned to suffer a horrible contraction… . It is hard to believe that financial services create enough value to command such pre-eminence in the economy. ( The Economist , 2009 )

For such a transition to be effective, two difficult tasks must be accomplished. Efficient financial theory must be replaced as the guide to policy making by the more realistic theories associated with Keynes and Minsky, and domination of financial policy making by the Lords of Finance must end.

The design and implementation of the changes needed in financial markets is a political as much as an economic challenge. Unfortunately, most elected officials responsible for overseeing US financial markets have been strongly influenced by efficient market ideology and corrupted by campaign contributions and other emoluments lavished on them by financial corporations. Between 1998 and 2008, the financial sector spent $1.7 billion in federal election campaign contributions and $3.4 billion to lobby federal officials ( Wall Street Watch , 2009 , p. 17). Moreover, powerful appointed officials in the Treasury Department, the SEC, the Federal Reserve System and other agencies responsible for financial market oversight are often former employees of large financial institutions who return to their firms or lobby for them after their time in office ends. Their material interests are best served by letting financial corporations do as they please in a lightly regulated environment. We have, in the main, appointed foxes to guard our financial chickens.

Unfortunately, the people President Obama has selected to guide his administration's financial rescue and reregulation programmes are almost uniquely unqualified to accomplish the dual objectives of down-sizing financial markets and eliminating dangerous securities. Chief economic advisor Lawrence Summers is a former Treasury Secretary who in 1999 supported the repeal of the 1930s legislation that separated investment and commercial banking, thereby legalising the creation of giant financial conglomerates and dramatically increasing the share of the industry that was ‘too big to fail’. Uniting commercial bank deposit and loan operations with investment banks and hedge and private equity funds was dangerous, yet Summers applauded Congress for refusing to regulate ‘a system for the 21st century [that] will better enable American companies to compete in the new economy’ ( Labaton, 1999 ). When Congress considered regulating financial derivatives trading, including CDSs, Summers told Congress that consideration of such legislation ‘cast a shadow of regulatory uncertainty over an otherwise thriving market’ ( Wall Street Watch , 2009 , p. 44). 13 Current Treasury Secretary Geithner and Summers were both protégés of Robert Rubin, a former chairman of Goldman Sachs and former Treasury Secretary, and currently an influential advisor to President Obama. The proposal to regulate financial derivatives ‘was quashed by opposition from [Clinton's] Treasury Secretary Robert Rubin…’ ( Wall Street Watch , 2009 , p. 17).

As president of the New York Federal Reserve Bank, Geithner had responsibility for seeing that giant financial conglomerates such as Citigroup avoided excessive risk, a task at which he failed miserably. He neither restrained their risk-taking nor warned the public that they had become excessively risky. ‘Mr. Geithner's five years as president of the New York Fed [was] an era of unbridled and ultimately disastrous risk-taking by the financial industry’ in which he ‘forged unusually close relationships with executives of Wall Street's giant financial institutions’ ( Becker and Morgenson, 2009 ). Geithner also bears substantial responsibility for the inefficiency of the financial rescue operations undertaken to date. For example, much of the Troubled Asset Relief Program in effect used taxpayer money to finance bonuses for top bank employees and dividends for shareholders with no positive impact on financial market performance.

Between 1998 and 2008 Rubin was a top official at Citigroup, where he received a cumulative $150 million in compensation. His main impact on bank policy was to push for the kind of aggressive risk taking that crashed the firm. Rubin ‘believed that Citigroup was falling behind rivals like Morgan Stanley and Goldman, and he pushed to bulk up the bank's high-growth fixed-income trading, including the CDO business’ ( New York Times , 2008 ).

At every stage, Geithner et al. have made it clear that they still have faith in the people who created the financial crisis—that they believe that all we have is a liquidity crisis that can be undone with a bit of financial engineering, that ‘governments do a bad job of running banks’ (as opposed, presumably, to the wonderful job the private bankers have done), that financial bailouts and guarantees should come with no strings attached. This was bad analysis, bad policy, and terrible politics. This administration, elected on the promise of change, has already managed, in an astonishingly short time, to create the impression that it's owned by the wheeler-dealers. ( Krugman, 2009 )

Until this administration adopts a radical change of course in its financial market policies, US and global financial markets are likely to remain fatally structurally flawed. 14

The ideas in this paper are drawn from Structural Causes of the Global Financial Crisis: A Critical Assessment of the ‘New Financial Architecture ( Crotty, 2008 ). Issues treated here are also addressed in other publications ( Crotty, 2009 ; Crotty and Epstein, 2009 ). I am grateful for research support from the Economics Department at UMASS through the Sheridan Scholars program and to Douglas Cliggott and Rob Parenteau for helpful advice.

Google Scholar

Google Preview

See Crotty (2002) for an explanation of the historical economic and political processes through which the neoliberal regime came to replace Golden Age institutions and practices.

An analysis of the effects of perverse incentives in different market segments is presented in Crotty, 2008 .

Ratings agencies also gave large investment banks like Lehman and Merrill Lynch solid investment grade ratings that allowed them to borrow cheaply. ‘It's almost as if the higher the rating of a financial institution, the more likely it was to contribute to financial catastrophe. In pursuit of their own short-term earnings, [ratings agencies] did exactly the opposite of what they were meant to do: rather than expose financial risk they systematically disguised it’ ( Lewis and Einhorn, 2009 ).

‘As late as April 5, 2007, one analyst at a major rating firm said their ratings model didn't capture “half” of a deal's risk…’ ( Wall Street Journal , 2009B ).

The collapse of Merrill Lynch resulted in the firing of chief executive Stan O'Neill. This episode demonstrates the power of perverse incentives: O'Neill received exit pay of $161 million for his part in destroying the firm.

Regulators simply accepted bankers’ assurance that they would sell these assets quickly: they did not check whether in fact this was true.

SIVs contributed to the non-transparency of financial markets. ‘The largest Citigroup SIV is Centauri Corp., which had $21 billion in outstanding debt as of February 2007… There is no mention of Centauri in its 2006 annual filing with the Securities and Exchange Commission’ ( Wall Street Journal , 2007C ).

‘AIG, due to its high credit rating, did not have to post collateral until it was downgraded. At that point, the collateral calls were so massive that they effectively made the insurance giant insolvent’ ( Financial Times , 2009D ).

See Bookstabber (2007) and Das (2006) for concrete examples of the risk- and complexity-augmenting properties of structured financial products.

Half of the spectacular rise in investment bank's return on equity in the four years leading up to the crisis was generated by higher leverage rather than smart investing, efficient innovation or even boom-induced capital gains on trading assets.

A study of the career choices of Harvard undergraduates found that the share entering banking and finance rose from less than 4% in the late 1960s to 23% in recent years ( New York Times , 2009B ).

Global financial assets have declined in value by $50 trillion ( Financial Times , 2009C ).

In 2008 Summers received $5.2 million for part-time service as an advisor to a hedge fund, and was paid $2.7 million for speaking appearances, including at banks such as Citigroup, Goldman Sachs and JP Morgan. Revelation of these facts ‘threatened to undermine public trust in the administration's economic plans’ ( Financial Times , 2009E ).

It is possible, but not likely, that Europe will act independently of the USA and aggressively reregulate their financial markets.

Email alerts

Citing articles via.

  • Contact Cambridge Political Economy Society
  • Recommend to your Library

Affiliations

  • Online ISSN 1464-3545
  • Print ISSN 0309-166X
  • Copyright © 2024 Cambridge Political Economy Society
  • About Oxford Academic
  • Publish journals with us
  • University press partners
  • What we publish
  • New features  
  • Open access
  • Institutional account management
  • Rights and permissions
  • Get help with access
  • Accessibility
  • Advertising
  • Media enquiries
  • Oxford University Press
  • Oxford Languages
  • University of Oxford

Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University's objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide

  • Copyright © 2024 Oxford University Press
  • Cookie settings
  • Cookie policy
  • Privacy policy
  • Legal notice

This Feature Is Available To Subscribers Only

Sign In or Create an Account

This PDF is available to Subscribers Only

For full access to this pdf, sign in to an existing account, or purchase an annual subscription.

IMAGES

  1. What Caused the Current Economic Crisis Term Paper

    thesis about economic crisis

  2. Global Economic Crisis

    thesis about economic crisis

  3. Research on the impact of economic crisis on child poverty and well

    thesis about economic crisis

  4. (PDF) Economic Crisis of Pakistan Essay Outline.pdf

    thesis about economic crisis

  5. (PDF) THE GREAT FINANCIAL CRISIS AND HOW THE PHILIPPINES GOT AWAY FROM IT

    thesis about economic crisis

  6. Difference Between Financial Crisis and Economic Crisis

    thesis about economic crisis

COMMENTS

  1. Full article: Factors Influencing Crisis Management: A

    Further, the depression in 1929–1933 and the financial crisis of 2007–2008 are some examples of economic and financial crises that affected the world. Accordingly, organizations confront a fast-changing environment with complex issues, difficulty in controlling the flow of messages, and managing various stakeholders (Strauβ & Jonkman ...

  2. A comparative analysis of COVID-19 and global financial

    This study aims to examine the impact of the global financial crisis, and the COVID-19 pandemic on the macroeconomic variables of the US economy. It also provides an understanding in a descriptive format, to analyze and compare the global financial crisis and COVID-19 pandemic, in a tabulated and graphical format.

  3. Structural causes of the global financial crisis: a critical

    The main thesis of this paper is that, although problems in the US subprime mortgage market triggered the current financial crisis, its deep cause on the financial side is to be found in the flawed institutions and practices of the current financial regime, often referred to as the New Financial Architecture (NFA). (While the global crisis ...